Phillips Curve Nonlinearities in the Data

Over the period of the Great Moderation, has inflation responded linearly to the output gap?

With GDP surging 4.1% SAAR in the third quarter [0], I soon expect to hear cries of inflation fears (example here). But it’s important to remember that even this rapid growth leaves a large output gap, on the order of 5%, expressed in log terms. (Note that I guesstimate the CBO’s potential GDP by applying the ratio of 2011 GDP’s in 2005Ch.$ and 2009Ch.$.)

nlinpix1.jpg
Figure 1: Real GDP (blue) and potential GDP from February 2013 (gray). Potential GDP in Ch.05$ adjusted to Ch.09$ using ratio of 2011 actual GDP. NBER defined recession dates shaded gray. Source: BEA, CBO, NBER, and author’s calculations.Even with the pieces apparently in place for accelerated growth, I don’t believe inflation is an imminent concern. That’s because of what the data — as opposed to what some “theories” (e.g., money base increase necessarily causes inflation) — seem to indicate. In particular, here’s a scatter plot of CPI inflation and lagged output gap, 1986Q1-2013Q1:

nlinpix2.jpg
Figure 2: CPI inflation measured as log first difference versus output gap in Ch.05$ (blue circles) and Loess curve (red), fitted using local tricube weighting and 0.7 bandwidth. Source: BLS, BEA 2013Q1 3rd release, and CBO Budget and Economic Outlook (February 2013), and author’s calculations.I rely upon the pre-benchmark GDP data because I have CBO estimates that are consistent with these data.

Interestingly, the slope coefficient is essentially zero from output gaps from -8% to -3% (log terms). From -3% to about 4%, the slope is positive, averaging about 0.21. Notice this pattern shows up if the personal consumption deflator is substituted for the CPI.

nlinpix3.jpg
Figure 3: Personal consumption expenditure deflator inflation measured as log first difference versus output gap in Ch.05$ (blue circles) and Loess curve (red), fitted using local tricube weighting and 0.85 bandwidth. Source: BEA 2013Q1 3rd release, and CBO Budget and Economic Outlook (February 2013), and author’s calculations.Obviously, this is not conclusive proof of an asymmetric Phillips curve. In particular, I’m only examining a nonlinearity in a bivariate scatterplot. Other variables one might think of interest – particularly expected inflation – are not included. As pointed out by others (e.g., Krugman), the expected inflation term does not seem of particular importance during the era of the Great Moderation, perhaps because of the anchoring of expectations.

nlinpix4.jpg
Figure 4: Median expected inflation one year ahead (blue), five year ahead (red), and ten year ahead (green). NBER defined recession dates shaded gray. Dashed lines indicate beginning/end of sample used in scatterplots in Figures 2 and 3. Source: Philadelphia Fed Survey of Professional Forecasters.In other words, inflation expectations stabilized considerably post 1985, at least as measured by the SPF.

This phenomenon suggests that the typical Phillips curve specification:

πt = πet + f(yt-1-y*t-1)

can be reduced to:

πt = α + f(yt-1-y*t-1)

where α is equal to a constant expected inflation representing anchored expectations, π is inflation, and “e” superscript denotes expected variable, y is log output and y* denotes log potential output.

Estimating the relationship over the 1986Q1-2013Q1 period, using a dummy variable to allow for a slope change when the output gap is larger than -0.03 yields the following results.

πt = 0.030 + 0.15×(yt-1-y*t-1) + 0.14×(yt-1-y*t-1) × POSDUMMYt-1

Adj.-R2=0.4 0.04, SER = 0.020, DW = 1.47; bold indicates significant coefficient at 5% msl, using HAC robust standard errors. POSDUMMY is a dummy variable that takes on a value of unity when the output gap is greater than -0.03.

The coefficient on the interaction term, while not significant at conventional levels, is significant at the 41% msl. Taken literally, the slope nearly doubles when the output gap is larger than -3%.

Assuming expected inflation equals lagged inflation yields an economically and statistically insignificant on expected inflation, which validates the specification adopted. Moreover, adding in the lagged inflation rate of oil prices improves the fit (Adj.-R2 = 0.17), but the same pattern holds: the slope coefficient doubles, from 0.12 to 0.24.

Bottom line: The economy could accommodate more monetary and fiscal stimulus without encountering high inflation.

For a skeptical view on nonlinearity associated with potential, see Ball and Mazumdar (2011).Coibion and Gorodnichenko (2013) argue that household inflation expectations are not as well anchored. Earlier posts on nonlinear aggregate supply here and here.

This piece is cross-posted from Econbrowser with permission.