Currency Wars and (Macro) Competitiveness

With the cover page of the Economist [1] [2] worrying about currency wars, and various analysts arguing whether the US can or cannot win such a “war” (see Naked Capitalism for a discussion), I thought it would be useful to see where we now stand, in terms of “competitiveness”, as understood by open economy macroeconomists.

 

currencywarcover.jpg 
Competitiveness
Open economy macroeconomists typically defined competitiveness as the relative price of traded goods. Below, I’ve plotted the trade weighted value of the dollar against a broad basket of currencies in nominal (blue) and real (CPI deflated) terms (red), as measured by the Federal Reserve. Notice that by this definition, “up” is an appreciation.
 
compet1.gif 
 

Figure 1: Nominal trade weighted value of the US dollar against a broad basket of currencies (blue), and real, CPI-deflated (red). Blue square is for 10/15 observation. An appreciation is denoted by an upward movement. Source: Federal Reserve Board.What is interesting is that the dollar is weakening against other currencies, including the East Asian currencies. (For calculations regarding the Chinese yuan, see here.) Much of the depreciation has occurred as talk of QE2 has mounted.

The CPI-deflated value of the dollar has also depreciated. It’s important to note that, as I discussed here [paper], the CPI might not be the most appropriate deflator, since it includes many nontradable goods and services; and in fact there is a theory which states that real exchange rates should appreciate over time as productivity rises relative to partner countries (see [3] [4]).

One might be more interested in the cost of produced goods, as opposed to price (see for instance this paper by Golub, as well as this paper). This suggests the use of unit labor cost deflated real exchange rates. In Figure 2, I plot the ULC deflated value of the dollar.

compet2.gif

Figure 2: Log real (CPI-deflated) trade weighted value of the US dollar against a broad basket of currencies, from IMF (blue), log real, CPI-deflated from Federal Reserve (red), and log unit labor cost deflated from IMF (green). (1) the ULC deflated series pertains to industrial countries. (2) An appreciation is denoted by an upward movement. Source: Federal Reserve Board, IMF, International Financial Statistics.Note because it is difficult to obtain ULCs for many emerging market economies on a timely basis, the ULC-deflated index pertains to a narrow basket of currencies, excluding China. This limits the usefulness of the measure, but one can still see how US productivity and wage trends affect the index. Arguments that high labor costs have made US goods uncompetitive (at least relative to a couple years ago) seem unjustified. (One caveat: as pointed out in this post, divisia indices potentially miss out on big level effects.

Limits to Expenditure Switching

I find it interesting that some people have argued that a depreciating currency will not have a large impact on US output. I tend to agree, but arguments based on low price elasticities of trade (as in this post), do not seem entirely convincing to me. In the past, I would have agreed that US trade (particularly import) elasticities with respect to the real exchange rate are low [5]. However, my more recent estimates, based on data going through 2010Q2, indicate the long run elasticity of exports is close to unity, suggesting scope for substantial impact from dollar depreciation [6] [paper].

Just because the US dollar has depreciated does not mean that we can necessarily “win” the currency wars. In fact, I’m not sure what “winning” means in this context. In particular, Barry Eichengreen notes that a far better way to stimulate economies would be in a coordinated fashion, with transparent declarations of what quantitative easing means and goals would be.

On the other hand, I do think the US can influence the US dollar real exchange rate even if other countries (including China) are less than willing to cooperate. Paul Krugman has observed that quantitative easing that involves further purchases of short term Treasury debt will have limited impact on exchange rates given the high substitutability of money and (short term) bonds at the zero interest bound. I have two observations: (i) if long term bonds are purchased, then quantitative easing/credit easing should have an impact, given the lower degree of substitutability. (ii) while no countries are on a classical gold standard right now (in contrast to the interwar years), if quantitative easing leads to more inflation than would otherwise occur, that would induce more rapid depreciation of the dollar. Of course, (ii) incorporates a big “if”.

The Fed has another tool, which it is unlikely to fully utilize, that could have a big impact on the dollar — namely changing the interest rate paid on reserves. That rate influences the money multiplier that links money base to the money supply. And I think few doubt that an expansion of the money supply has an impact on the exchange rate.

A cooperative solution to monetary policy (and macro policy coordination) [7] is clearly more desirable than a noncooperative solution. But in the absence of that, there are actions that can be undertaken to improve the US situation.

Update 9:10pm More on QE2 and currency wars from Alan Taylor, Manoj Pradhan and Joachim Fels in a Morgan Stanley note discussed here. PIIE’s Arvind Subramanian thinks the US cannot the currency war.

The quantitative impact of QE2 depends on the magnitude of the purchases. Chris Neely’s results, discussed in this post, is summarized thusly in a recent Deutsche Bank Global Economic Prospects:

…the St Louis Fed has calculated that a total of $1.725trn asset purchases resulted in an accumulated decline in the dollar of 6.5%. On this basis, a $1 trn purchase of Treasuries might therefore cause the dollar to decline by 4%. …(Peter Hooper and Torsten Slok, September 29, 2010)

The Neely results are contained in this paper.


Originally published at Econbrowser and reproduced here with the author’s permission.
 
All rights reserved. Opinions and comments on RGE EconoMonitors do not necessarily reflect the views of Roubini Global Economics, LLC, which encourages a free-ranging debate among its own analysts and our EconoMonitor community. RGE takes no responsibility for verifying the accuracy of any opinions expressed by outside contributors. We encourage cross-linking but must insist that no forwarding, reprinting, republication or any other redistribution of RGE content is permissible without expressed consent of RGE.    
    

 

One Response to "Currency Wars and (Macro) Competitiveness"

  1. Neven strmski   October 24, 2010 at 12:08 pm

    I was researching more today on the Fed.’s probable QE2 policy. I came to wonder why no one has tied together a reasonable scenario for possible positive effects of this quantitative easing. I believe that the focus of QE2 will have several likely effects if and when successful. First of all, there is likely a positive correlation between the timing of the Fed.’s QE2 and: 1. the midterm election in the U.S., 2.the lackluster state of the current domestic economy ( pretty obvious ), 3. the recent foreclosure problems in the US, 4. the USA’s promotion of free-floating global currencies. There is no doubt in my mind that these 4 issues are positively correlated.The Fed plans to use this blunt but powerful instrument known as QE2 to stimulate the domestic economy by effecting all four of these issues at the same time. This policy has the potential to take some of the mortgage-back securities off the books of the US Treasury, help the big banks better deal with the current housing foreclosure issues and slowly help the banks increase their lending. At the same time, QE2 can provide a fresh start ( or a new homeostasis ) for the currency valuations of countries around the world that have pegged their currencies to a benchmark (such as the US dollar ) and not allowed their currencies to float. Realistically, what can other countries do to retaliate? Probably not much. And lastly, just several weeks away from the US midterm elections, this policy may stimulate the financial markets and prove to be a ” shot in the arm ” for Democrats in the coming elections.I believe that in the short to medium term, QE2 will help address 3 or even all 4 of these above mentioned issues. Three out of four ain’t bad, but if all four were addressed, QE2 would be considered one of the US Federal Reserves’ shining moments in history.